Corporate-controlled capitalism in India
NEELANJAN SIRCAR
IN September 2020, three controversial farm acts passed by the
Parliament gave way to one of the largest protest movements in recent history.
But the protests were about much more than IndiaÕs agricultural policy –
and they had significant resonance beyond the farmers of Haryana and Punjab
that were most affected by the controversial farm bills.1 Rather, the larger critique made by the
farmer protests coalesced around a criticism of bowing to Ôcorporate interestsÕ
supported by the ruling Bharatiya Janata Party (BJP). In my view, the farmer
protests had great impact and resonance, eventually causing the government to
rescind the laws, due to popular anxieties about the changing face of business-politics
relations in India.
In this piece, I
chronicle the extraordinary level of economic centralization and corporate
consolidation taking place in India today. I attempt to theorize how this
consolidation is both a result of the prevailing political environment in
India, and how it perpetuates greater political and economic centralization. I
hope this short piece encourages others to focus research and commentary on the
unprecedented levels of economic centralization we are seeing in India today
and its impacts on society.
A common refrain
is that levels of economic centralization and inequality we see today in India
are a natural consequence of capitalism and economic markets. But as any
scholar of political economy knows, competitive markets, capitalism, and state
intervention have had radically different consequences for economic
centralization across countries. To properly analyze the structural shifts in
IndiaÕs political economy today, we need a more nuanced understanding of how
states manipulate economic markets and make larger economic policy.
At the outset,
let us distinguish between three types of state-business relations in
capitalism that have consequences for economic concentration: laissez-faire
capitalism, state-controlled capitalism, and corporate-controlled capitalism.2
The first type, laissez-faire
capitalism, is a model in which the government follows a principle of
minimal government intervention in the functioning of economic markets, while
allowing for legal frameworks that support competitive markets. In this model,
entrepreneurs, firms and labour bargain in a ÔdecentralizedÕ fashion,
responding to incentives of market competitiveness, to shape the overall
economy. A prototype of this model is found in Anglo-American contexts like the
United States.3
The second type,
state-controlled capitalism, is a model in which the state actively
intervenes in the market, often to manipulate incentives for companies and to
boost exports in privileged market sectors. Chalmers Johnson famously described
these states as Ôdevelopmental statesÕ in contrast to the Ôregulatory statesÕ
that govern laissez-faire capitalism.4 The prototypes of the state-controlled
capitalism model are successful economies in East Asia like Japan and China.5
The third type, corporate-controlled
capitalism, is a model in which macro-economic policy is strongly guided by
the interests of the largest business (corporate) actors. In this model, the
structure of the economy is strongly shaped by the proximity of entrepreneurs
and large firms to political power and thus the levers of policymaking. The
prototypical case is post-Soviet Russia (particularly under the leadership of
Boris Yeltsin), although it has been observed in many countries transitioning
from socialist economies.6
Naturally, the type of capitalism in a
country has implications for the pattern of economic centralization likely to
be observed.7 State-controlled capitalism is likely to
generate less economic centralization than other models of capitalism, as the
state ostensibly represents the interests of a broad swath of the public. In
laissez-faire capitalism, corporate actors are free to consolidate wealth, but
the regulatory stateÕs focus on maintaining competitive markets prevents the
extreme economic centralization that would occur from oligopolistic and
monopolistic pricing. In corporate-controlled capitalism, the wealthiest
persons are able to influence policy in ways that are likely to generate
disproportionate benefit to themselves, by creating oligopolistic arrangements
or through the purchase of previously state-owned assets, suggesting a
particularly high level of economic centralization.
To understand how the level of economic
centralization among the super-wealthy in India compares to those resulting
from these types of capitalism, I compare economic centralization in India with
that of China, Japan, Russia, and the United States. One intuitive measure of
the concentration of wealth in this super wealthy class is to look at share of
national income attributed to the
top
1% of the highest earners. Figure 1 displays the share of income for the
top 1% across these five countries, as calculated by The World Income Database
developed by scholars at the Paris School of Economics and UC Berkeley.
There are several
key points to be gleaned from figure 1. The end of World War II (and
colonialism in India) ushered in a sharp drop in economic centralization, but
this trend has been steadily reversing around the world from the 1990s onward.
Nonetheless, there are
key differences across countries. Consistent with the framework described,
those countries with state-controlled capitalism, China and Japan, demonstrate
structurally lower levels of economic concentration of wealth, while the the
United States displays significantly higher economic centralization than cases
of state-controlled capitalism. However, India and Russia demonstrate the
highest economic centralization among this group of countries; in fact, IndiaÕs
share income to the top 1% of the population (21.7%) is estimated to be
slightly higher than that of Russia (21.4%), which is particularly worrying
given that Russia is seen as the prototypical case of corporate-controlled
capitalism.
In India,
economic centralization has accelerated faster than much of the world in the
wake of the economic liberalization reforms in the 1990s. Although it does not
display the levels of economic centralization observed in Russia during the
most extreme abuses of the Boris Yeltsin era, India is today displaying
unprecedented levels of economic centralization – even more than the
pre-independence era.
While the data establish that India has seen
worrying levels of economic centralization, this need not imply corporate
consolidation and policy-making influence. Indeed, Thomas PikettyÕs magisterial
work chronicling rising inequality across the world has more to do with the
return on inherited wealth than corporate consolidation per se.8 Nonetheless, this pattern of income
generation merits closer scrutiny on profit generation for the largest Indian
corporates.
To understand the level of corporate
consolidation, I rely on recent analyses of the profit share of IndiaÕs most
profitable firms. A recent analysis by Krishna Kant9 reports nearly 65% of all corporate
profits accrued to the top 20 firms (see figure 2), a slight dip from a high
above 70% in fiscal year 2020 but much higher than the period before 2014 when
the Bharatiya Janata Party (BJP) came to power. Indeed, this profit share was
less than 50% as recently as fiscal year 2011. These data tally closely with
the work of Saurabh Mukherjea and Harsh Shah at Marcellus,10 who have calculated a similar metric back
1994. These analyses agree on a simple fact: the scale of corporate
consolidation, as measured by profit share, has significantly grown in the
post-2014 period especially after IndiaÕs demonetization exercise.
At first blush, the level of corporate
consolidation in India since Narendra Modi became prime minister might be
surprising. Prime Minister Modi has overseen extensive political centralization
predicated on his personal appeal11 and even sought to bring certain key
corporate personalities like Vijay Mallya to task. A similar misconception
exists about Vladimir Putin in Russia, who has centralized power in the country
and famously expropriated Yukos Oil from Mikhail Khodorkovsky. Yet, a closer
look at Russia reveals that Putin has cultivated an extensive network of
ÔoligarchsÕ – RussiaÕs super-wealthy business elite – who are loyal
to him.12 While
political centralization requires the filiality of a countryÕs corporate elite,
it is also likely strongly dependent upon its wealth (as I document in some
detail below).
How might this corporate consolidation have
taken place in India? As in Russia, there have been concerns that IndiaÕs
corporates are able to wrangle previously state-owned assets to bolster their
wealth. A key example of this phenomenon is the purchase of six airports
previously controlled by the Airport Authority of India (AAI) by Gautam Adani
in 2019. Indeed, the AAIÕs employee union recently alleged that assets and
equipment were sold to Adani at well below market valuations.13 With the purchase of Air India from the
government, the Tata Group now has controlling in stakes in three airlines
– Air India, AirAsia, and Vistara – that can plausibly fly
international routes from India (Air India and Vistara already have permission
to do so, and AirAsia is in the process getting a permit).
Relatedly,
concerns have been raised that Mukesh AmbaniÕs Reliance Group was given
preferential treatment by the government in setting up operations in the
telecom sector and now has the largest market share in the sector.14 The perception of proximity to government
also makes a company a more attractive destination for foreign direct
investment (FDI). Indeed, while India showed record-breaking FDI in the
previous fiscal year, more that 40% of FDI inflows were captured by AmbaniÕs
Reliance Group due to a large investment in Jio from Facebook in that year.
In short, the
noticeable corporate consolidation in the past few years seems to be about much
more than market behaviour. Rather, the sale of state assets and preferential
political treatment are alleged to be significant factors in the consolidation.
This has also skewed the pattern of foreign investments in the country,
creating a feedback loop for greater consolidation.
The growing economy, combined with greater
levels of electoral competition from the 1990s onward has ushered in a period
of increasingly wealthy individuals entering the political arena and financing
their own campaigns.15 This fundamentally changed the social profile of
candidates. Indeed, Gilles Verniers has shown that by 2017, 50% of Uttar
PradeshÕs elected members of legislative assembly (MLAs) were businessmen
compared to less than 10% in the 1980s. These businessmen were were predictably
drawn from ÔlocalÕ sources of wealth, like real estate and transport.16
But these
ÔlocalÕ sources of wealth also pose problems for any political actor seeking
centralize power. First, the Ôaaya Ram, gaya RamÕ politics of party
defection and floor crossing of legislators and candidates is a well known
phenomenon. If the sources of capital are local in nature, then the volatile
nature of party membership induces bargaining and complex concessions to local
capital. Second, as Kanta Murali has shown persuasively, differences in local
business interests can generate different economic policies from state to state
especially if local capital has a significant role to play in financing
politics.17
The greater economic concentration and
corporate consolidation observed since the BJP came to power enables the
political centralization project of the government in important ways. Large
corporations likely generate revenue at an all-India level and abroad, and thus
their demands are more likely to be
ÔnationalÕ and less ÔlocalÕ in nature – which should advantage the party
at the Centre. Furthermore, as figure 2 suggests, demonetization has almost
certainly decimated many sources of local capital, which was often derived from
real estate and corruption in local contracts. In sum, economic centralization
and corporate consolidation implies that corporates with ÔnationalÕ preferences
are likely to play a much bigger role in politics – and may offer the
financial backbone for political centralization.
Significant
political centralization in India has been observed in India since the BJP came
to power in 2014 across, among other things, welfare policy and federalism18 to the role of the BJPÕs central
leadership in state-level campaigns.19 Fundamentally, this consolidation
requires the Ôcentralization of political appealÕ to Prime Minister Narendra
Modi. In order to achieve this outcome,
the ruling BJP must mobilize significant financial resources in deploying media
resources and funding party machinery.20
Corporate-controlled capitalism need not
imply that corporate actors become direct policymakers. Rather, it need only be
the case that fostering political centralization and fostering corporate
consolidation is Ôincentive compatibleÕ for both political actors and business
interests. In such a scenario, political actors willingly adopt policies that
foster such corporate consolidation. Indeed, the scale of funds required for
political centralization and the demands raised by increasingly wealthy big
capital generate natural complementarities. A small number of highly profitable
firms with national-level demands should find it easier to negotiate with a
strong, unitary actor at the Centre, rather than a fractured coalition or a
collection of different regional leaders. Similarly, the Centre should find it
easier to negotiate between and inculcate loyalty between a small number of
business actors.
In this way,
there is a symbiotic relationship between political and economic
centralization. The desire for political centralization creates incentives to
create a small number of loyal wealthy corporate actors, who then wield greater
influence in policy – generating corporate-controlled capitalism. This
creates a feedback loop for even greater economic centralization.
The relationship between big capital and
political financing has undoubtedly been strengthened through IndiaÕs
controversial electoral bond scheme, which allows for large-scale donation in
an anonymous manner. Anonymity is
key for political financing from businesses, as parties do not want to be seen
as biased in favour of any particular business and businesses do not want to be
perceived as enga-ging in corruption. Furthermore, the anonymity does away with
plausible spending limits for political financing. Now, a small number of
business actors holding a disproportionate amount of
the countryÕs profits may plausibly provide for a significant portion of a
partyÕs financial needs. With greater levels of political centralization, the ruling
government is more capable of manipulating economic policy if it should choose
to do so.
According to
analysis of party funding in fiscal year 2019-2020 by the Association for
Democratic Reforms (ADR), 70% of funding for national parties comes from Ôunknown
sourcesÕ. Among these unknown sources, 90%
is attributable to electoral bonds.21 Notably, the ruling BJP has received more
than 78% of its funding from unknown sources – which is 3.5 times higher
than funding from unknown sources for all other national parties combined. (It
is worth noting here
that even for regional parties, 55% of funding comes from unknown sources.)22
As I have argued here, two patterns are
particularly worrying in understanding the role of IndiaÕs corporates in
political financing. First, the desire for political centralization for the
ruling party, and the fact that policies encouraging corporate consolidation
are incentive compatible may lead to the manipulation of national economic
policy. Second, the opaque nature of party funding implies that
a small number of corporate actors can plausibly provide significant money to
parties in exchange for preferential treatment. Nonetheless, it is important to
note that none of what I have shown necessarily implies political corruption or
even illegal activities pursuant to laws around political financing.
In popular discourse, politics is disproportionately discussed through the lens of electoral behaviour. In academic discourse, too, there is a greater emphasis on studying the characteristics of individual legislators and local politics. However, the larger trends in the country are showing political and economic centralization growing in tandem – and this I believe is the core structural shift taking place in the political economy of India today. In this piece, I have tried to offer a simple set of logics which offer plausible explanations for the extraordinary economic concentration of wealth we are seeing in India today, and how it relates to policymaking. However, far more detailed empirical work is needed to truly understand the structural shifts we are observing in IndiaÕs political economy.
Footnotes:
1. Neelanjan Sircar, ÔWhere the State Failed to Build a Credible Case for Agricultural ReformsÕ, Hindustan Times, 29 November 2021. https://cprindia.org/sites/default/files/Where%20the%20State%20failed%20to%20build%20a%20credible%20case% 20for%20agricultural%20reforms.pdf.
2. To be clear, the characterization of various models of capitalist economies is a vibrant (and at times contentious) literature, and this typology will necessarily cut across other theorized classifications of economies. My aim with this categorization is to focus on the key agents in framing policies for domestic economic markets.
3. Of course, some deviations from this model take place in the United States from subsidies in agriculture to differential taxation policy.
4. Chalmers Johnson, Japan, Who Governs? The Rise of the Developmental State. W.W. Norton & Company, 1995.
5. In framing this discussion, I am deliberately sidestepping a larger debate on the Ôvarieties of capitalismÕ, which separate economies in to Ôliberal market economiesÕ and Ôcoordinated market economiesÕ. This characterization (and its criticism) has led to a fruitful debate on the structure of economies, demonstrating, among other things, a significant amount of variation in the role of the state in various East Asian economies.
See Peter A. Hall and David Soskice (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. 1st edition. Oxford University Press, Oxford and New York, 2001.
6. This pattern of policymaking is closely related to what is commonly called Ôcrony capitalismÕ in which entrepreneurs use political proximity to extract benefits for themselves – although crony capitalism need not imply that entrepreneurs influence policy as in corporate-controlled capitalism.
7. Of course, the assumption in this typology is that the leadership is interested in wealth generation for some segment of the countryÕs citizens and residents and not just personal wealth (e.g., a ÔkleptocracyÕ).
8. Thomas Piketty, Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Reprint edition. Belknap Press, Cambridge and London, 2017.
9. Krishna Kant, ÔProfit Concentration in India Inc Rises amid Private Sector GrowthÕ, Business Standard News, 25 November 2021, https://www.business-standard.com/article/companies/profit-concentration-in-india-inc-rises-amid-private-sector-growth-121112500070_1.html.
10. Saurabh Mukherjea and Harsh Shah, ÔIndiaÕs Top 20 LeviathansÕ Awe-Inspiring DominanceÕ, Marcellus, 2021, https://marcellus.in/blogs/indias-top-20-leviathans-awe-inspiring-dominance/.
11. Neelanjan Sircar, ÔThe Politics of Vishwas: Political Mobilization in the 2019 National ElectionÕ, Contemporary South Asia 28(2), 2020, pp. 178-94.
12. Roman Dobrokhotov, ÔHow Putin Became a Problem for Russian OligarchsÕ, 24 December 2017, https://www.aljazeera.com/opinions/2017/12/24/how-putin-became-a-problem-for-russian-oligarchs.
13. Jagriti Chandra, ÔAdani Got Assets at 3 Airports for a Song, Says AAI UnionÕ, The Hindu, 5 October 2021, https://www.thehindu.com/news/national/aai-assets-worth-1300-cr-at-3-airports-sold-to-adani-for-500-cr-claims-union/article36835561.ece.
14. V. Venktaswara Rao, ÔThe Rise of Monopolies in ÒNew IndiaÓ,Õ Deccan Herald, 19 November 2020, https://www.deccanherald.com/opinion/panorama/the-rise-of-monopolies-in-new-india-917337.html.
15. Neelanjan Sircar, ÔMoney in Elections: The Role of Personal Wealth in Election OutcomesÕ, in Costs of Democracy. Oxford University Press, Delhi, 2018, https://oxford.universitypressscholarship.com/10.1093/oso/9780199487271.001.0001/oso-9780199487271-chapter-3.
16. Gilles Verniers, ÔThe Transformation of Backward Class Politics in Uttar PradeshÕ, Economic and Political Weekly 53(33), 18 August 2018, pp. 7-8.
17. Kanta Murali, Caste, Class, and Capital: The Social and Political Origins of Economic Policy in India. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2017.
18. Yamini Aiyar and Neelanjan Sircar, ÔUnderstanding the Decline of Regional Party Power in the 2019 National Election and BeyondÕ, Contemporary South Asia 28(2), May 2020, pp. 209-22.
19. Neelanjan Sircar, ÔThe Welfarist Prime Minister: Explaining the National-State Election GapÕ, Economic and Political Weekly 56(10), March 2021, pp. 7-8.
20. Sircar, 2020.
21. Association for Democratic
Reforms, Analysis of Sources of Funding of National Parties – Fiscal
Year 2019-2020, 2021,
https://docs.google.com/viewerng/viewer?url=https://adrindia.org/sites/default/files/Analysis_of_sources_of_funding_
of_National_Parties_FY2019-20_Hindi.pdf.
22. Association for Democratic Reforms, Analysis of Donations Received by Regional Parties – Fiscal Year 2019-2020, 2021, https://adrindia.org/content/analysis-donations-received-regional-political-parties-fy2019-20-0